The results to last week's Fun Online Poll were pretty conclusive:
What do you think caused the poor visibility that led to the M5 pile up?
Fog - 61%
Smoke - 8%
Other, please specify - 30%
I'm glad to see that most of you share my cynical view that they only tried to blame it on the fireworks because of this knee-jerk reaction that Somebody Is To Blame and Something Must Be Done. And if that involves Banning Something Which Is Pointless But Fun, then so much the better, of course. The most interesting comment was this one, which I shall have to take at face value:
Ryan: I know somebody who was in the accident. It was caused when a small car pulled out of the slip-road between two lorries. One of these lorries put on its brakes hard causing it to jack-knife and everyone else piled into it. Nothing to do with fireworks (ended ages before apparently).
Which suggests that the accident wasn't even caused by poor visibility in the first place, a thought which hadn't even occurred to my cynical mind. Although it seems beyond dispute that visibility was bad at the time (having ruled out fireworks, we are left with fog), which may have made the crash worse than otherwise.
--------------------------------
My recent post on crisps attracted a (to me) staggering twenty-five comments, people were naming crisp brands which I had long forgotten (or never heard of). I didn't realise that so many other people had such strong views on the topic. So that's this week's Fun Online Poll: "Which is your favourite brand of crisps?"
Vote here or use the widget in the sidebar.
--------------------------------
Next week: "What's your favourite type of nuclear reactor?" Suggestions as to the best way of classifying the basic types welcome.
Tuesday, 15 November 2011
Fun Online Polls: M5 pile up and crisps
Posted by
Mark Wadsworth
at
09:16
10
comments
Labels: Bansturbation, Crisps, Fireworks, FOP, Motorways, Nuclear power
Monday, 14 November 2011
Faceless Bureaucrat
Posted by
Mark Wadsworth
at
20:03
0
comments
Labels: Caricature, EU, Italy, Mario Monti
"Police shoot cow that nearly trampled boy in Chandler"
From azfamily.com
CHANDLER, Ariz. -- Police say they had to shoot a cow that was on the loose in Chandler.
The cow was on the run about 7 p.m. Sunday in the area of Queen Creek and Alma School roads. Officers said the cow got aggressive and nearly trampled a 9-year-old boy. Andy Gallardo said he got a small scrape on his shin but is OK. The cow was running into traffic when officers say they were forced to open fire.
There is no word on how the cow got loose.
That seems a bit harsh to me.
Posted by
Mark Wadsworth
at
16:14
2
comments
Didn't Robert Maxwell get into trouble for doing something like this?
From The Telegraph:
Europe's €1 trillion (£854bn) rescue fund has been forced to buy its own debt as outside investors become increasingly concerned about the worsening eurozone sovereign debt crisis.
The European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF) last week announced it had successfully sold a €3bn 10-year bond in support of Ireland. However, The Sunday Telegraph can reveal that target was only met after the EFSF resorted to buying up several hundred million euros worth of the bonds.
Sources said the EFSF had spent more than € 100m buying up its own bonds to help it achieve its funding target after the banks leading the deal were only able to find about €2.7bn of outside demand for the debt.
How people can still refer to the EFSF as a €1 trillion fund when it is quite clear that the 'fund' has no money of its own and struggles to raise €2.7 billion is a mystery to me.
Posted by
Mark Wadsworth
at
13:58
5
comments
I can see this going horribly wrong...
From The Daily Mail:
... it also emerged today that the London Organising Committee of the Olympic and Paralympic Games (Locog) has underestimated the number of security guards needed nationally for the event.
Locog had originally thought it would need 10,000 guards, but, after a review over the summer, now believes it will need up to 21,000, according to The Guardian. Security firm G4S, which won the contract to provide initial security for the Games, is said to be this week preparing a recruitment drive to make up the shortfall.
Now they've advertised this, presumably UK based terrorists will be applying in droves on the off-chance that a few of them manage to slip through the vetting procedures.
Posted by
Mark Wadsworth
at
12:19
4
comments
Health Scare Story Du Jour
From The Daily Mail:
For those keen to look after their health, sugar-free fizzy drinks may seem a wise choice. But they could actually increase the risk of having a heart attack or stroke, research shows.
A study of more than 2,500 people found those who had diet drinks every day were 61 per cent more likely to get vascular problems than those who did not have any carbonated drinks.
Researcher Hannah Gardener said: "If our results are confirmed with future studies, then it would suggest that diet soda may not be the optimal substitute for sugar-sweetened beverages for protection against vascular outcomes."
Posted by
Mark Wadsworth
at
11:41
7
comments
Labels: Bansturbation, Food, Health
Sunday, 13 November 2011
"South African farmer killed by pet hippopotamus"
Spotted by Diogenes in The Telegraph:
Earlier this year Mr Els was pictured happily riding on his pet bull hippo’s back.
“Humphrey’s like a son to me, he’s just like a human,’ he said at the time, “There’s a relationship between me and Humphrey and that’s what some people don’t understand. They think you can only have a relationship with dogs, cats and domestic animals. But I have a relationship with the most dangerous animal in Africa.”
Mr Els kept 20 different species of exotic animals including giraffe and rhino on his farm near Klerksdorp in South Africa’s north west. But he developed a special fondness for Humphrey, whom he bought aged just five months and for whom even built a special lake.
Humphrey was aged six and weighed more than a metric ton when he attacked Mr Els. Hippos are considered to one of the world’s most dangerous animals. They are, by nature, very aggressive – especially when young calves are present. They commonly attack humans with no apparent provocation, usually using their enormous canine teeth to gouge their victims. They can weigh up to three tons and can travel at speeds of up to 30mph.
There's one born killed every minute.
Posted by
Mark Wadsworth
at
19:07
7
comments
Killer Arguments Against LVT, Not (175)
Bayard, who is not totally anti-LVT, came up with this one:
"... what I see as a genuine problem with LVT [is] the other side of the "free rider" effect so often highlighted on this blog (e.g. railway company spends millions of pounds opening a new station and everyone in the vicinity benefits from the increased land value without having to do a thing).
This happened in a town near me, where a run-down market town was transformed over a few years into a thriving, happening place by the efforts of a group of shopkeepers and other traders. They invested their time and money and suffered reduced profits to build the place up and, for a while, reaped the reward. Then, of course, rents in the town started to rise and so business rates went up, and much or all of the increased profit disappeared in the higher rates.
Or, to take a more extreme example, on many landed estates in the C18th and C19th, it was not worth the tenants doing anything to improve their farms, as the resulting increase in revenue would be entirely clawed back by the landlord in increased rent. "
To understand why this isn't a 'genuine problem', you have to:
a) be able to distinguish truly earned income (from running in or working in a business) from land rental income. It is then a case of matching the costs of running a business with the costs of owning land, and
b) be aware of market forces and the effect of competition.
1. The C18th and C19th landed estates issue is easily dealt with, of course there was little or no incentive for tenant farmers to improve their farms, but that is because they were expected to bear the costs of improving the land out of their earned income, while the extra income from the improvements was collected by land owners. In a free market, it would be the land owners who pay for the improvements and recoup the cost by charging higher rents, in the same way as most landlords are happy to pay for decoration and repairs to the housing they own as long as the extra rent they can collect it more than covers the cost.
2. If all the shopkeepers in Bayard's example were tenants, then the same logic applies. It is quite probable that the extra rents and Business Rates soaked up most of (call it two-thirds of) the extra profits they could earn, but for an owner-occupier shopkeeper, the extra Business Rates is only about a third of that two-thirds, so they were still massively ahead of the game; part of their extra profits were truly earned and part were simply because they happened to own land in an area where 'everybody else' is paying for improvements.
3. Then we have to remember the impact of free-market competition:
i. Let's assume that there are ten hairdressers in the area, all open 9-5 six days a week and there is demand for a hundred thousand hair cuts a year, so that's 4.0 hair cuts per shop per hour during normal opening times or 10,000 hair cuts per shop (2,500 hours x 4). And let's call it £10 per hair cut.
ii. Now, maybe one hairdresser is keen to earn a bit extra and opens an hour earlier and stays open an hour later to snaffle the early morning and late evening trade and his gamble pays off. The average number of hair cuts per hour now falls to 3.9, our entrepreneur does an extra 2,000 hair cuts a year (3,100 x 3.9 minus 2,500 x 4.0) and earns an extra £20,000 and all the other hair dressers notice that they are now only doing 9,750 hair cuts a year (2,500 x 3.9), suffering a loss of income of £2,200 each (figures rounded).
iii. If the other hair dressers are just as keen, then they will all extend their opening hours accordingly, until they recapture that lost income, and they will keep extending their opening hours as long as the extra income is sufficient to pay their earned income or wages for being in the shop (whether actually cutting hair or just waiting for customers). If they all open an hour earlier and stay open an hour later, then on average they end up doing 3.22 hair cuts an hour and they all end up doing 10,000 hair cuts a year (3,100 x 3.22) and earning the same amount of money. Who gains from all this competition - the customer, of course.
iv. Clearly, there is an upper limit; there is no point opening at five o'clock in the morning or staying open until midnight, because very few people want to have their hair cut at such an inconvenient time. But the fact that competition only helps the individual hairdresser in the short run and benefits the customer in the long run - when gains are competed away - is the whole argument in favour of free competition.
4. The same applies to collective efforts done to improve the whole area, whether this is paid for by the shopkeepers or the local council doesn't matter. If one high street becomes relatively more attractive, then sure, the people on that street will earn extra income, part of which is earned (supplying goods and services) and part of which is unearned (the fact that their premises are now in a more favourable location).
5. For sure, a full-on LVT would soak up the bulk of the unearned element, and the earned element would be entirely untaxed (under full-on LVT there is no income tax or VAT), but does this discourage groups of shopkeepers from getting together to improve their area? No, of course not - because the extra LVT is still a lot less than the overall extra income!
6. Furthermore, by and large, one high street's gain is another high street's loss. Shopkeepers in the unimproved areas will see that their takings and profits fall, and so the rental value and hence LVT bills also fall, but because the fall in LVT is less than the fall in takings and profits, they end up worse off. So what is their best strategy? It is of course to try and improve their area to recapture some of that lost trade.
7. With the hairdressers in example 3, they all extend their opening hours and end up with the same income as if they'd formed a cartel and restricted opening hours and customers end up with a better deal, as they can pop in before work or after work etc. it would be the same with the shopkeepers in an unimproved area near the improved area; the only way to claw back that trade is to do the same improvements, which boosts their income at the expense of all other areas (including the already improved one).
8. Sooner or later (hopefully) most or all areas will become improved and the incomes and rents will settle down to the old level - but we'll end up with much nicer high streets, longer opening hours etc etc. Or perhaps, once most areas are improved, they will end up snaffling all the trade that was formerly spread over a wider area, so they are using land more efficiently and the last couple of areas become marginal for shops and so we can use these for housing or something else.
9. I suspect that shopkeepers seldom make co-ordinated collective efforts to improve their area (there would still be a free rider problem - the minority of shopkeepers or owners of vacant premises who do not contribute will still benefit), in which case the local council is in the same position as the C18th and C19th land owners from example 1 or a residential landlord. The landlord knows it's worth putting in new carpets for £500 every three years if he can get £200 a year extra rent. But he's no incentive to fit brand new Persian rugs every year at a cost of £1,000 because tenants won't pay that much extra. We end up with the optimum quality carpets in rented flats.
10. If the council can spend £x million on providing more free car parking spaces, sweeping the pavements, having more bobbies on the beat, putting up Xmas decorations, having more benches or wider pavements, getting more bus services etc, and knows that this pushes up rental values so that the extra LVT income is >£x million they will do it. But there is an upper limit to what is worth spending money on, an extra fifty parking spaces might be a no brainer, and an extra hundred might be better than fifty, but there is no point in buying up and knocking down buildings and then losing the LVT therefrom in order to provide a thousand free car parking spaces.
11. And there is also competition between councils in the same way as there is competition between hairdressers (from 3) or different groups of shopkeepers (from 8). And however you argue it, we are still far better off taxing land values rather than earned income - not least because taxes on earned income increase the cost of carrying out the improvements in the first place, i.e. those improvements are normal earned income from the point of view of the car park builders, street sweepers, policemen, Xmas decoration installers etc and if these people have to pay income tax, it pushes up the market clearing price for their services.
Posted by
Mark Wadsworth
at
14:18
20
comments
Labels: Economics, Free markets, KLN, Land Value Tax
Saturday, 12 November 2011
Killer Arguments Against LVT, Not (174)
1. It's pretty clear that many arguments against Land Value Tax are based on a complete absence of understanding or appreciation of how free markets work, which is how they end predicting a variety of apocalyptic outcomes if we were to abolish taxes on income and output and just make everybody pay the same price for occupying land in any area, regardless of the use to which it is put (commercial or residential). As far as land use is concerned any changes would be fairly marginal, incremental and all beneficial (there'd be more efficient use of land).
2. Despite all the distortions introduced by the system of land ownership and subsidies to land ownership and NIMBY imposed planning restrictions and the abuse thereof by e.g. certain supermarket chains and 'home builders', things still tend to level out in the end. For example, I live in a commuter suburb with one Tube station where 95% of the land is used for housing and the rest for shops and schools. The 'catchment area' of the Tube station is larger than comfortable walking distance, so there is demand for a car parking places at the station.
3. There must be some optimum ratio of car parking spaces-to-housing/population, but what is the best way of working out whether we have too few, enough, or too many parking spaces? Surely, the best way is to compare the rental income (expressed per square yard) you can earn by using one square yard of land for a car park with the same the rental income you can earn by building and renting out a house.
4. If there were too few parking spaces, then the rental income from the car park would exceed the rental income from housing, and it would make commercial sense to buy up some more houses near the station, knock them down and expand the car park. This would reduce the clearing price for parking spaces, and it would make sense to continue with this policy until the rental value of the car park falls to the rental value of surrounding housing.
5. Conversely, if there were too many parking spaces, the reverse would apply and it would make sense to use part of the car park for residential housing etc.
6. As it happens, the population of the suburb is 10,000 and there are fifty car parking spaces at the station. We can safely assume that this is a fairly optimum ratio because we know that the rental values of car parking spaces and of housing is about the same (about £45 - £48). It may be that the town planners or Transport for London decided the number of parking spaces abitrarily, or on the basis of what happens elsewhere, but that does not matter, because with LVT there would be no need for such detailed planning.
7. I haven't adjusted those rental figures for the relative cost of building/maintaining a house and building/maintaining a car park, but part of the cost of the latter would involve buying up existing houses and knocking them down (which would wipe out any incremental gain). There is however one big distortion in the tax system: the car park is liable to Business Rates which takes about thirty per cent of the gross rent, and the houses are only liable to Council Tax, which only takes about ten per cent of the gross rent. If both uses were liable to tax at exactly the same rate, and any further income generated from the improvements not taxed at all, then surely we are far more likely to get the optimum number of car parking spaces (which might be seventy or eighty, I do not know).
8. So, let's get the Killer argument in question which has been bugging me for a while, it was Sobers, here, who said:
"if a postcode has a land usage in it that is very high in value - a supermarket say, that the LVT value per sq ft is going to be very high in that postcode? So any other business that shares the postcode with the supermarket will have to pay a massively higher LVT as a result?"
9. He has no evidence to suggest that supermarkets can generate a lot more in income/profit per square yard than other uses, but let's assume that they do, and let's start with a clean sheet. So, we draw up our rough plans for an entirely new town, say where the station, the roads and the parks will be and give an indication as to what we expect the population to be.
10. We could auction off the land and not collect any tax at all; or we could give away the land for free but make it liable to LVT. Either way, we invite applications from people who want to build or own houses or supermarkets or offices etc. If we set the rate too high, then we won't get our town filled up and if we set it too low, we'll be losing revenue, but by some sort of auction process, we'll arrive at the right figure.
11. Now, it may well be the case that a supermarket can generate more income than other uses, but there are diminishing returns to increasing the size of a supermarket, once it has reached a certain size (largely dictated by how big the population of the town will be), the marginal return from occupying another square yard of land would be less than the cost of occupying that square yard and that puts the free market upper limit on the size of the supermarket.
12. And all other users will be paying the same rate, entirely voluntarily (OK, in practice we'd have at least three rates, one for town centre and one for suburban and one for industrial estate, the bit near the motorway junction, along the railway tracks or near to sewage works). Those who can earn the most money from living or doing business there will of course end up better off than those who earn least, but even the people who are earning least will be able to afford to live there, because the price (the selling price of LVT rate per unit of land) is set by the amount lowest successful bid. And low-value added or specialist businesses will be able to make do with smaller premises further off the beaten track, if they aren't willing and able to make enough money to pay the bare minimum, then the town would be better off if a more profitable business took their place.
13. Similarly, most people think it's nice to have a big back garden rather than a postage stamp, but again, there are diminishing returns to scale. There is a huge net increase in enjoyment by having fifty square yards rather than none, so people will pay a lot extra for fifty square yards; it's a lot nicer having a hundred rather than fifty; it's a bit nicer having a hundred and fifty rather than a hundred and so on. But once you are past a certain stage, having a larger garden becomes a burden to the owner rather than a benefit.
14. So the free market discipline of making the land available for a uniform price would encourage people to choose the optimum size for their back gardens as well. Whether that comes out at five or ten or twenty houses per acre does not matter. And those who aren't interested in back gardens (or can't afford one) will make the corresponding tax saving by not having one or living in a block of flats.
15. The BIG difference between selling off the land tax-free and giving it away subject to LVT is that with a sale, the original optimum position is frozen for all time and if demand changes, then supply does not adjust and there will be windfall gains and losses in future, but with LVT the auction process and optimisation process are a permanent: actual use of land will respond much more quickly to demand and there is little downside risk; if the new town project is a failure, then the LVT rate will fall but at least you paid nothing for the land. If it is a success, then people will be willing and able to afford a higher LVT rate. Those who aren't will quickly be replaced by people who are.
Posted by
Mark Wadsworth
at
15:10
24
comments
Labels: KLN, Land Value Tax
Friday, 11 November 2011
We own land! Give us money!
From Housing Excellence:
Housing Minister Grant Shapps today reassured anxious homeowners struggling to pay their mortgages of the wide range of support available to help them keep their homes, and ensure that repossession remains the last resort...
The Minister made clear that just as the Government is providing help* for people wanting to get on the property ladder, a range of support* is also available to keep them in their homes and avoid the threat of repossession... Also over the next two years the Government is investing more than £200 million into the Mortgage Rescue scheme. The scheme, available through local authorities, is designed to offer a last resort to the most vulnerable families to avoid repossession...
Notwithstanding that £200 million is a drop in the ocean, isn't this just another example of The New Maths or something? There's a fixed amount of housing, so for every household 'helped to stay on the property ladder' there is another household who are being prevented from 'getting on the property ladder'.
Whichever group you subsidise, you end up with higher house prices and higher profits for the banks, and if you subsidise both you just double up this effect. Conversely, if we scrapped the equal and opposite subsidies, we'd probably end up with a higher level of owner-occupation, at a fair old saving to the taxpayer.
*"Help" and "support" are NewSpeak for "give money to".
Posted by
Mark Wadsworth
at
13:23
21
comments
Labels: Grant Shapps MP, Maths, Newspeak, Subsidies